Water fetching and firewood collection are among home activities that are part of the daily routine of many households in rural Ethiopia. Households travel long distances and spend large amounts of time every day for collecting water and firewood. Fetching water and firewood reduce labor available for market related activities such as agriculture that affects production and productivity of these sectors negatively. Better access to water facility and energy efficient technology (such as improved stoves) is expected to release labor for market related activities that can have economy-wide impacts. The objective of this study is to investigate the economy-wide effects of access to water facility and improved stoves.
Methods
The study uses the updated 2004/05 Social Accounting Matrix (SAM) of Ethiopia. The SAM is modified to account for a detailed representation of water fetching, firewood collection and leisure activities and commodities. This study applies a single country Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) model to the updated SAM of Ethiopia. The simulation scenario is a 50% increase in the Total Factor Productivity (TFP) of both water fetching and firewood collection activities due to better access to water infrastructure and cooking improved stoves.
Results
The findings of the study show that better access to drinking water supply and improved stoves reduces labor time spent for water fetching and firewood collection. The released labor from water fetching and firewood collection partly reallocated to leisure consumption and partly to market related activities. Those freed labors that are reallocated to marketed sectors including agricultural and non-agricultural activities leads to increase employment and enhance domestic production. Better access to drinking water and improved stoves also enhances household welfare. Households that allocate a relatively large proportion of labor to water fetching and firewood collection gain relatively more welfare. Macroeconomic indicators such as GDP, total domestic production, absorption, and imports are also positively affected due to improved access to water and energy efficient technology.
Conclusions
It is helpful to recognize the economic significance of labor released from water fetching and firewood collection in any developing economy with a limited supply of water facility and access to energy technology.
Background
Access to drinking water and household energy are among the development challenges of developing countries. Approximately, 663 million people around the world lack access to improved drinking water; out of this, 50% live in Sub-Saharan Africa. The target of the United Nation Millennium Development Goal (UNMDG) to reduce the proportion of population without sustainable access to drinking water by half between 1990 and 2015 was unachievable by most of Sub-Saharan Africa countries but there are some on-going positive changes. However, Ethiopia is among one of the countries that successfully achieved this target. During 1990 only 13% of the Ethiopian population had access to improved water but in 2015 half of the population is able to get improved water sources (WHO and UNICEF 2015).
However, the majority of Ethiopian households are currently unable to access drinking water close to their neighbourhood. Only 12% of the Ethiopian population has access to piped water (WHO and UNICEF 2015). The main sources of drinking water for Ethiopian households include public standpipe, protected/unprotected dug well/spring, ponds, lakes and rivers (WHO and UNICEF 2010). These sources of water are usually located far from the neighbourhood of the household. The majority of Ethiopian households often spend several hours per day for collecting drinking water from remote sources. For instance, 16% of urban and 34% of rural household on average travel between 1 and 2 h per trip for water fetching. In rural areas of Ethiopia, household spent a longer hours for fetching water. For example, 10% of rural household on average travel more than 2 h per trip for collecting water (Fig. 1).
Fig. 1
Source: Author’s compilation based on Central Statistical Agency (2014)
Classification of Ethiopian households by water fetching time per round trip
Ethiopia is also a country where the majority of the population has limited access to electricity. More than 75% of Ethiopians live without access to electricity. Nearly all rural households and 80% of urban households in Ethiopia depend on biomass fuel for cooking (International Energy Agency 2014). Biomass fuel is sourced from firewood, animal dung, and crop residue. The majority of households use a traditional cooking stove which is less energy efficient (Rehfuess et al. 2006). Furthermore, due to underdeveloped road infrastructure and deforestation, households travel long distances and spent several hours for collecting firewood. For example, 22% and 36% of urban and rural households spent more than 2 h per trip to collect firewood respectively (Fig. 2).
Fig. 2
Source: Author’s compilation based on Central Statistical Agency (2014)
Classification of Ethiopian households by firewood collection time per round trip
Therefore, Ethiopian households allocate significant quantity of labor for water fetching and firewood collection activities. Furthermore, water fetchers and firewood collectors are usually agricultural laborers in Ethiopia. Specifically, fetching water and firewood reduces labor time available for marketed sectors including non-agricultural activities that adversely affects production and productivity of these sectors. The time spent for fetching water and firewood can be significantly reduced through improved access to water infrastructure, and household energy saving technology (for example, improved stoves). The freed labor from water and firewood collection can be partly reallocated to marketed activities or partly reallocated to leisure. Labor reallocated to market related activities would have tremendous economy-wide implications.
Previous studies incorporate aggregate home activities including care of children and the elderly, cooking, cleaning, fetching water and collecting firewood in the CGE model such as Fontana and Wood (2000). Little or no attempts were made to distinguish between the varieties of home activities. Different types of home activities satisfy different objectives and are accomplished by different technologies. Therefore, the innovation of this study is separately depicting labor-intensive home activities such as water fetching and firewood collection and leisure into the economy wide model. The objective of this study is to investigate the economy-wide effects of better access to water facility and improved stoves.
Materials and methods
Data
This study uses the updated 2004/05 Social Accounting Matrix (SAM) of Ethiopia (Mosa 2018). The original 2005/06 SAM of Ethiopia was built by Ethiopian Development Research Institute (EDRI) in cooperation with the University of Sussex (Tebekew et al. 2009). Mosa (2018) updated the 2004/05 SAM of Ethiopia with a detailed representation of water fetching, firewood collection and leisure activities and commodities. Since water fetching and firewood collection are performed by households, distinct water fetching and firewood collection activities are added to the updated SAM in accordance with household classification. Following the approach developed by Fontana and Wood (2000) a separate activity and commodity accounts are created for leisure. Since households consume leisure, leisure activities are added to the SAM in accordance with household classification. Furthermore, distinct commodity accounts are also created for water fetching, firewood collection and leisure. Transactions for water fetching, firewood collection and leisure in the SAM are computed based on the value of labor time allocated to these activities. The values of labor time spend for water fetching, firewood collection and leisure activities are computed based on the shadow wage of labor.
The updated micro-SAM has 199 activities and 95 commodities, 34 representative household groups that are categorized by agro-ecological zones, poverty status and source of non-agricultural income, 10 labor categories that are classified by gender and occupations and 21 other factors of production such as capital and land that are differentiated by agro-ecological zones. The SAM also has 17 tax accounts and other core accounts such as government, investment and the rest of the world. The updated SAM comprises 481 row and column accounts. The updated balanced macro SAM of Ethiopia is depicted in Table 1. Furthermore, the detail micro SAM accounts is provided in Appendix 1.
Table 1 Macro SAM of Ethiopia (in billions Ethiopian birr)
This study applies Static General Equilibrium (STAGE) model (McDonald 2007) to the updated SAM of Ethiopia (Mosa 2018) STAGE is a single country CGE model. It is a Social Accounting Matrix (SAM) based CGE model that has linear and non-linear relationships that govern the behavior of agents in the model. Households choose a bundle of commodities to consume in order to maximize Stone-Geary utility function. The commodities consumed by households are a composite of imported and locally produced commodities. The constant elasticity of substitution (CES) is used to combine imported and locally produced commodities by assuming that these commodities are imperfect substitutes using the Armington assumption (Armington 1969).
Several types of model specific elasticities are used in the calibration of the CGE model applied for this study. Elasticities in the model include commodity, activity and income elasticities. Commodity elasticities involve Armington’s substitution elasticities between imported and domestically produced commodities and the elasticities of transformation between local commodities and export commodities. The commodity elasticities also include export demand elasticities and substitution elasticities for aggregation of commodity output. Activity elasticities cover elasticities of substitution between intermediate inputs and value added input and the substitution between different primary factors such as labor, capital and land in the nested production function. Income elasticities are elasticities for the consumption of different commodities by households. In this study, commodity, activity and Frisch elasticities are adopted from Flaig (2014). On the other hand, most of the income elasticities are adapted from Tafere et al. (2010).
Policy simulations
Simulation scenarios
The construction of drinking water infrastructure around the vicinity of households and providing access to energy technology (such as improved cooking stoves) potentially reduce the time spent on water fetching and firewood collection. This would improve the efficiency of collecting water and firewood as less labor would be required to collect the same amount of water and firewood. Therefore, this study analyses the scenario of an increase in the Total Factor Productivity (TFP) of water fetching and firewood collection activities due to improved access to drinking water and energy technology.
The quantity of labor time freed in response to better access to drinking water supply depends on agro-ecological zone and place of residence (rural vs. urban). This complicates the estimation of the exact amount of time saved because of improved access to drinking water infrastructure. However, the value of time saved from water fetching can be approximated in a certain range of intervals. For instance, Cook et al. (2013) in Oromia region of Ethiopia reported that improved access to water supply can successfully reduce water fetching time by 35% to over 90% per day. Accordingly, in this study, it is assumed that improved access to drinking water supply can reduce the time spent for fetching water on average by 50%.
Similarly, the amount of time saved due to improved access to household energy relies on access to modern cooking technology and availability of traditional source of energy. Empirical evidence by Gaia Consulting Oy and Ethio Resource Group (2012) in Ethiopia indicates that access to improved stove reduces household’s fuel consumption by more than 50%. This led to approximately 50% less firewood collection time. Accordingly, in this study, it is also assumed that in response to improved access to household energy saving services (for example, improved stove), efficiency of firewood collection activities can be increased on average by 50%.
Therefore, the simulation scenario is 50% increase in the TFP of both water fetching and firewood collection activities in response to improved access to water and household energy saving technology.
The cost of financing water and energy infrastructure are obtained from domestic sources or international donors (loans and grants). Specifically, the main sources of financing water and energy infrastructure in Ethiopia are government treasury, user contributions and support from international donors. Indeed, approximately three-fourth of the total national water supply budget is sourced from the treasury of government and the remaining share is covered by international donors and user contribution (World Bank 2016).
In the policy scenario, the funds for constructing drinking water and energy facilities are sourced from government savings and foreign savings (loans and grants). In other words, in order to finance the construction of water infrastructure and energy efficient technology, government savings and foreign savings are exogenously increased in the model. Since government treasury is the largest source of funds in the national water supply budget, the larger share of funds is obtained from the government savings relative to foreign savings. The total government savings are 5.4 billion birr and foreign savings are 10.9 billion birr in the updated SAM.
For approximating the effect of government expenditure on reducing water fetching and firewood collection time, expert opinions and estimates of the budget required for achieving universal water access as defined by the UNMDG are used in this study. According to experts’ opinion, 0.5 to 1.5 h per day per household from water fetching can be saved in Sub-Saharan African countries by achieving universal access to water i.e. a 50% reduction in the share of population that is unable to secure improved drinking water (World Health Organization 2012). Therefore, for this study it is assumed that if Ethiopia achieved universal water access, the average water fetching time will be reduced by 50%.
According to World Bank (2016), the aggregate budget required for achieving universal access to water in Ethiopia is 16.7 billion birr. The country already spent 13.6 billion birr in the year 2012. Therefore, it is assumed that an extra 3.1 (16.7–13.6) billion birr investment is needed for achieving universal water access (World Bank 2016). It is also assumed that the required fund (3.1 billion) is generated through a 37% increase in government savings (i.e. 2 billion birr) and a 10% increase in foreign savings (i.e. 1.1 billion birr). Therefore, for financing water and energy infrastructure, government savings exogenously increase by 37% and foreign savings increase by 10%. Since the government and foreign savings are not channelled to investments, the multiplier effects are not accounted for in this simulation.
Model closure rule
The exchange rate is flexible while the external balance is fixed in the model. The exchange rate is flexible to produce the fixed level of foreign savings for funding water infrastructure and energy efficient technology. Investment driven savings is chosen where investment is fixed and savings are flexible in the model such that savings adjust for the saving-investment balance. Alternatively, savings driven investment closure can be chosen where savings are fixed but investment is flexible to adjust the saving-investment balance to generate the required level of funds for the construction of water and energy infrastructure.
Government raises funds through income tax replacement. Government savings are fixed and income tax rates are endogenously adjusted to produce a fixed level of government savings for financing the construction of water infrastructure and energy efficient technology. Alternatively, government investment (expenditure) is fixed and income tax rates are endogenously adjusted to produce a fixed level of public expenditure for financing water and energy infrastructure. The consumer price index (CPI) is chosen as a numeraire. Furthermore, factor supplies are fixed in the model and in order to enable the mobility of water fetcher and firewood collectors across different sectors, perfect factor mobility is assumed in the model.
Results and discussion
The study examines the impact on labor reallocation across sectors, domestic production, domestic price and household consumption, household’s welfare and implication on major macroeconomic indicators.
Effect on labor reallocation
In rural Ethiopia, water fetching and firewood collection is commonly accomplished by reducing the daily agricultural labor time. On the other hand, in urban parts of the country, unskilled workers commonly collect water and firewood. Water fetching and firewood collection are labor-intensive household activities. An improved TFP of water fetching and firewood collection results in reduction of labor required to perform these activities. Table 2 describes the change in labor demand across sectors in response to improved TFP of water fetching and firewood collection activities.
Table 2 Simulated changes (percentage) in labor demand across sectors
The simulation result indicates that because of a 50% rise in TFP, labor demand declines on average (weighted) by 22.3% for firewood collection and by 21.7% for water fetching activities. Because of better access to water facility, households consume additional water and relatively more labor is required to fetch the extra drinking water. Therefore, the labor demand for water fetching does not decline by the full 50%. On the other hand, employment of labor in agriculture, industry, and service activities increases on average by 1.6%, 0.9% and 0.5% respectively because of absorbing the released labor from water fetching and firewood collection. The agricultural sector absorbs a larger percentage of labor relative to industry and service sectors. This happens because large shares of water fetchers and firewood collectors are agricultural laborers in Ethiopia. Thus, when water fetching and firewood collection activities are effectively accomplished, agriculture absorbs a relatively larger proportion of freed laborers relative to other sectors (such as industry and service). Furthermore, most of the freed laborers prefer to enjoy extra leisure and hence labor is reallocated to leisure (4.6%).
Effect on domestic production
Table 3 depicts the change (weighted) in domestic production because of increased TFP of water fetching and firewood collection activities. Production of water fetching on average increases by 17.5% and firewood collection on average increases by 16.5% due to enhanced TFP. Furthermore, labor released from water fetching and firewood collection is transferred into other sectors and stimulates agricultural and non-agricultural (such as industry and services) production in the destination sector. Production of agriculture, industry and services on average increases by 1.2%, 0.6% and 0.4%, respectively, due to employment of extra labor which is attracted from water fetching and firewood collection. Production in the agricultural sector increases by a higher proportion relative to other sectors (industry and services).
Table 3 Simulated changes (percentage) in domestic production by sectors
Higher TFP in water fetching and firewood collection activities provides larger proportions of released labor for agriculture relative to industry or services and hence production in this sector increases more. Furthermore, the production of leisure increases by 4.6%, which is relatively greater than other sectors such as agriculture, industry, and services. This happens because there was less or no time left for leisure activities when household collects water and firewood from the distant sources and therefore, the freed labor prefers to enjoy leisure and hence more labors are reallocated to leisure. Additionally, the larger production of leisure can be explained by the fact that the consumption of leisure is more sensitive to the income changes relative to other commodities. Therefore, an increase in household income (due to reallocation of labor to income generating activities) raises the demand for leisure that leads to a more production of leisure.
Effect on domestic price and household consumption
In response to higher TFP in water fetching and firewood collection activities, a large amount of labor is released and reallocated to other activities. The labor reallocated to other sectors enhances domestic production (Table 3) and at the same time results in higher income for households through increased factor payments. The simultaneous rise in both domestic production and household income differently affects domestic prices and household consumption. Conceptually, increased domestic production results in higher commodity supply in the market and this can potentially reduce domestic supply prices of commodities (PQS) and purchaser prices (PQD). On the other hand, the freed labor from fetching water and firewood and subsequently reallocated to marketed sectors brings extra income to the households which increases household consumption demand (QCD). This potentially increases domestic prices.
Table 4 describes the percentage change (weighted) in domestic prices and household demand in response to higher TFP in water fetching and firewood collection. The simulation results indicate that because of higher TFP in water fetching and firewood collection, QCD increases for all commodities: agricultural by 1.7%, industrial by 1.3%, services by 0.6%, water fetching by 17.5%, firewood collection by 16.5% and leisure by 4.6%. Domestic prices for agricultural, industrial, and service commodities on average increase by 2.1% and for leisure commodities on average increase by 2.3%. This implies that the effect of increasing income dominates the price effect. The extra income results in upward shift in households’ consumption demand and hence increases domestic prices.
Table 4 Simulated changes (percentage) in domestic price and household demand
On the other hand, household demand for water fetching and firewood collection commodities increases but domestic prices for these commodities decrease on average by 32.2% and 32.1%, respectively. Household demand for water fetching and firewood collection increases by 17.5% and 16.5% respectively. This can be explained by the fact that because of efficiency gains in water fetching and firewood collection, large quantities of water and firewood are produced and supplied to the market. Water and firewood become relatively cheaper and hence consumption demand for these commodities increases (due to income and substitution effects).
Effect on household welfare
Increased TFP of water fetching and firewood collection also affects household welfare. Figure 3 shows the equivalent variation (EV) in percent of base income to examine the actual welfare changes across household groups. Welfare improvement happens to all groups of rural households but the amount of welfare gains varies among households. Different household groups allocate divergent quantities of labor for water fetching and firewood collection. Accordingly, welfare gains depend on household endowment of labor that can be potentially allocated to water fetching and firewood collection. In other words, households that allocate a relatively larger proportion of labor to water fetching and firewood collection obtain high welfare gains. For instance, non-poor and poor rural households in agro-ecology zones 1 and 5 allocate the highest proportion of labor to water fetching and firewood collection relative to other groups of households. Because of increase in the TFP of water fetching and firewood collection, welfare gains by these household groups are higher than to other household groups.
Fig. 3
Source: Author’s computation based on model results
Simulated changes (percentage) in household welfare (EV/base income)
On the other hand, the divergent share of water and energy consumption expenditure also results in different welfare gains across household groups. The share of consumption expenditure to water and energy commodities differs by household groups. Better access to water and energy infrastructure increases the supply of water and energy and these commodities become relatively cheaper. Households that spend a larger share of their consumption expenditure on water and energy commodities gain more welfare relative to others. For example, poor rural households located in agro-ecology zones 1 and 5 spend a larger proportion of consumption expenditure on water and energy commodities. Because of better access to water and energy facility, the welfare gains to these household groups are higher than to other household groups.
Similarly, the welfare of poor urban households is also positively affected by increasing TFP of water fetching and firewood collection. Since urban households allocate less labor for collecting water and firewood, their welfare gain is lesser than for rural households. However, the welfare of urban non-poor households is negatively affected. This can be explained by the fact that some portions of financing the construction of water and energy facility are obtained from government savings that are raised through income tax. Since urban non-poor households contribute, a larger share of tax to the government, their consumption expenditure decreases and hence welfare declines.
Macroeconomic effects
Reallocation of released labor from water fetching and firewood collection to other sectors creates economy-wide linkages and positively affects the macroeconomic indicators such as gross domestic product (GDP), total domestic production, absorption, import, export and exchange rate.
Figure 4 depicts the macroeconomic effect of higher TFP in water fetching and firewood collection. Total domestic production increases by 2%, GDP by 2.6%, absorption by 2.8%, imports by 1.5% and the exchange rate by 1.3%. The released labor from water fetching and firewood collection is reallocated to productive sectors that accelerate domestic production. This leads to an increase in domestic consumption (absorption) and import. Furthermore, reallocated labor promotes the growth of the economy and hence the GDP increases.
Fig. 4
Source: Author’s computation based on model results
The sensitivity of model results due to the change in the core model parameters such as the income elasticity of leisure is discussed in this section. Specifically, this section discusses the sensitivity of labor demand, domestic production, household welfare, and major macroeconomic effects due to the change in the income elasticity of leisure. Sensitivity analysis is carried out by changing the income elasticity of leisure from 2 to 3 (50% increase) and 4 (100% increase). The sensitivity of model results in response to the change in income elasticity of leisure is provided in Appendix 2. The percentage change in labor demand and domestic production varies when the income elasticity of leisure increases from 2 to 3 and 4. When the income elasticity of leisure is higher, a larger share of the freed labor gets into leisure and a smaller proportion is reallocated to other sectors (agriculture, industry and services) (see Appendix 2.1 for details).
Household welfare is not very sensitive to the change in the income elasticity of leisure. All groups of households except urban non-poor households have less welfare gains when the income elasticity of leisure increases from 2 to 3 and 4 (see Appendix 2.2 for the details). The reason is that leisure does not create multiplier effects through commodity demand. The macroeconomic indicators such as absorption, import demand, GDP from expenditure and total domestic production also slightly vary due to the change in the income elasticity of leisure. Specifically, absorption, import demand, GDP, and total domestic production increase by a lesser percentage when the income elasticity of leisure is higher (see Appendix 2.3 for the details).
Therefore, the change in the income elasticity of leisure leads to some changes in labor demand, domestic production, household welfare, and major macroeconomic indicators. Although the changes in the income elasticity of leisure result in slight disparities in the magnitude of simulation outcome, the direction of changes remains the same as well as the order of size.
Comparison of results with previous studies
The expansion of improved drinking water infrastructure has both costs and economic benefits. Some of the costs include investment cost (for example, cost associated with the initial construction of the water facility) and recurrent cost (for example, maintenance cost). The benefits of improved access to drinking water supply include health related benefits (for example, reduction of waterborne diseases, less mortality, avoidance of the loss of productive time due to diseases and saved health care expenditure) and the opportunity cost of travel and waiting time saved from fetching water.
The World Health Organization (WHO) estimates the benefit–cost–ratio (BCR) of universal access to improved drinking water for 136 low and middle-income countries in 2012 (World Health Organization 2012). These countries are grouped into nine sub-regions: South-Eastern Asia (S.E.Asia), Sub-Saharan Africa (SSA), Latin America and Caribbean (LAC), Southern Asia (S.Asia), Eastern Asia (E.Asia), North Africa (N.Africa), Western Asia (W.Asia), Caucasus and Central Asia (CCA) and Oceania. The BCR was estimated for individual countries initially and then it was aggregated to a region weighted by the respective country’s population.
According to the WHO’s study, the benefits of universal access to drinking water outweigh the costs for most of the countries (Fig. 5). Figure 5 depicts the BCR of universal access to improved drinking water across countries ranging from 0.6 in Oceania to 3.7 in S.Asia. Each additional dollar of investment provided for improved drinking water results in 0.6 to 3.7 dollar worth of benefits. The bigger proportions of these benefits are derived from the opportunity cost of labour time saved due to improved access to water supply.
Fig. 5
Source: Author’s compilation based on World Health Organization (2012)
BCR of improved access to water supply (US$ return per US$ invested)
On the other hand, improved access to household energy (for example, improved cooking stove) has costs and economic benefits. The costs include the purchase of stoves and installation cost among others. On the other hand, the benefits include health related benefits (reduction of diseases caused by IAP), less expenditure on health care services linked to IAP, productivity gain due to better health, time saved from cooking and fuel collection, environmental benefits (for example, fewer trees cut down). Figure 6 shows the BCR of reducing the share of the population without access to improved cooking stove by 50% across WHO sub-regions. The WHO regions are South-East Asia Region (SEAR), Western Pacific Region (WPR), Eastern Mediterranean Region (EMR), and Region of the Americas (AMR), African Region (AFR) and European Region (EUR).
Fig. 6
Source: Author’s compilation based on Hutton et al. (2006)
BCR of access to improved stove (US$ return per US$ invested)
The estimated BCR of access to improved cooking stove varies across different sub-regions; it ranges from 37.4 to 137.4 in AFR and WPR respectively. Each additional dollar of investments to provide improved stoves results in 37.4 to 137.4 worth of US dollar benefits. The largest share of benefits is derived from the saved time that would have been used for cooking and collecting firewood (Hutton et al. 2006).
Because of the difference in the methodologies used and in the context of case study area, it is not easy to compare the result of this study with the previous studies. Although the methodology applied and the case study areas in the previous studies mentioned above are varied, this study is in consistent with the findings of the previous studies that confirm the cost of providing water facility and improved stoves outweighs the benefits gained.
Conclusions
The findings of this study show that better access to water facility and improved stoves reduces the labor time spent for water fetching and firewood collection. Those freed labor are reallocated to agricultural, non-agricultural activities and/or leisure. This lead to increase employment in all sectors, and enhances domestic production. Households also enjoy extra leisure because of better access to water and energy infrastructure and overall welfare improved. Furthermore, the released labor facilitates aggregate domestic production, consumption and imports and hence growth of the economy. Although the simulation results are sensitive to the change in the income elasticity of leisure, the direction and order of magnitude of results are unaltered in all scenarios.
Improved access to drinking water and improved stoves has health and non-health related benefits such as reduction of waterborne diseases and indoor air pollution, saved health care expenditure, productivity gain due to better health and the time saved from water fetching and firewood collection. However, this study analyzes only the benefits of freed labor from water fetching and firewood collection due to improved access to water infrastructure and improved stoves. Therefore, the economic gains of better access to water and improved stoves are only partially captured by this study.
This study used static model. A similar future work can apply dynamic model for analyzing the time path of benefits derived from investment in water supply and improved stoves. Furthermore, the precision of behavioral parameters such as elasticities in the model can be improved by estimating the value of these elasticities using econometrics.
Availability of data and materials
Some of the data used for this study can be accessed from Ethiopian Development Research Institute. Other support data can be obtained from the corresponding author up on request.
Abbreviations
CGE:
Computable General Equilibrium
CPI:
Consumer price index
GDP:
Gross domestic product
EV:
Equivalent variation
EDRI:
Ethiopian Development Research Institute
Eyleisure:
Income elasticity of leisure
IEA:
International Energy Agency
PQS:
Domestic supply prices
PQD:
Domestic purchaser prices
QCD:
Household consumption demand
STAGE:
Static General Equilibrium Model
SAM:
Social Accounting Matrix
TFP:
Total Factor Productivity
UNMDG:
United Nation Millennium Development Goal
WHO:
World Health Organization
UNICEF:
United Nation International Children’s Fund
OECD:
Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development
References
Armington PS (1969) A theory of demand for products distinguished by place of production. IMF Staff Papers 16(1):159–178
Central Statistical Agency (2014) Ethiopia Time Use Survey 2013: Main Report. Addis Ababa
Cook J, Masuda Y, Fortmann L, Gugety MK, Smith-Nilson M (2013) How Does Improving Access to Rural Water Supply Change Household Time Use in Ethiopia? Draft January 2013. Seattle
Flaig D (2014) Factor Mobility and Heterogeneous Labor in Computable General Equilibrium Modeling Dissertation Submitted in Fulfilment of the Requirements for the Degree ‘Doktor der Agrarwissenschaften.’ Universität Hohenheim
Fontana M, Wood A (2000) Modeling the Effects of Trade on Women, at Work and at Home. World Dev 28(7):1173–1190
Gaia Consulting Oy, Ethio Resource Group (2012) Improved Cook Stoves: Final Report, GHG Mitigation and Sustainable Development Through the Promotion of Energy Efficient Cooking in Social Instituitions in Ethiopia. Helsinki
Hutton G, Rehfuess E, Tediosi F, Weiss S (2006) Evaluation of the costs and benefits of household energy and health interventions at global and regional levels. WHO, Geneva
International Energy Agency (2014) Africa Energy Outlook: A Focus on Energy Prospects in Sub-Saharan Africa. World Energy Outlook Special Report, Paris
McDonald S (2007) A Static Applied General Equilibrium Model: Technical Documentation STAGE Version 1: July 2007 Draft. Oxford
Mosa A (2018) Non-agricultural activities and household time use in Ethiopia: a computable general equilibrium model analysis. PhD Dissertation. University of Hohenheim, Stuttgart
Rehfuess E, Mehta S, Prüss-Üstün A (2006) Assessing household solid fuel use: multiple implications for the millennium development goals. Environ Health Perspect 114(3):373–378
Tafere K, Taffesse AS, Tamru S (2010) Food Demand Elasticities in Ethiopia: Estimates Using Household Income Consumption Expenditure (HICE) Survey Data (No. 011). Addis Ababa
Tebekew T, Amoge A, Teferra B, Seyoum Z, Amha M, Beyene H, Fisseha E, Tsehaye E, Ahmed H, Robinson S, Willenbockel D, Dorosh P, McDonald S (2009) Ethiopia Input Output Table and Social Accounting Matrix. Addis Ababa
WHO, UNICEF (2010) Rapid assessment of drinking-water quality in the federal democratic republic of Ethiopia: country report of the pilot project implementation in 2004–2005. WHO, UNICEF, Geneva
World Health Organization (2012) Global costs and benefits of drinking water supply and sanitation interventions to reach the MDG target and universal coverage (No. 12. 01). World Health Organization, Geneva
This paper is part of the corresponding author’s Ph.D. dissertation. The rest authors were supervisor (HG) and co-supervisor (KS) to the corresponding author. Therefore, the corresponding author was the major contributor, the co-author contributed through discussion, reading and approving the final manuscript. All authors read and approved the final manuscript.
The authors declare that they have no competing interests.
Additional information
Publisher's Note
Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Appendices
Appendix 1: Structure of the updated 2005/06 SAM of Ethiopia
1.1 Activity accounts
1.1.1 Agricultural activities
Abbreviations
Descriptions
atef1
Growing teff in zone 1
atef2
Growing teff in zone 2
atef3
Growing teff in zone 3
atef4
Growing teff in zone 4
atef5
Growing teff in zone 5
abar1
Growing barley in zone 1
abar2
Growing barley in zone 2
abar3
Growing barley in zone 3
abar4
Growing barley in zone 4
abar5
Growing barley in zone 5
awhea1
Growing wheat in zone 1
awhea2
Growing wheat in zone 2
awhea3
Growing wheat in zone 3
awhea4
Growing wheat in zone 4
awhea5
Growing wheat in zone 5
amaiz1
Growing maize in zone 1
amaiz2
Growing maize in zone 2
amaiz3
Growing maize in zone 3
amaiz4
Growing maize in zone 4
amaiz5
Growing maize in zone 5
asorg1
Growing sorghum in zone 1
asorg2
Growing sorghum in zone 2
asorg3
Growing sorghum in zone 3
asorg4
Growing sorghum in zone 4
asorg5
Growing sorghum in zone 5
apul1
Growing pulses in zone 1
apul2
Growing pulses in zone 2
apul3
Growing pulses in zone 3
apul4
Growing pulses in zone 4
apul5
Growing pulses in zone 5
avegfr1
Growing vegetable and nec in zone 1
avegfr2
Growing vegetable and nec in zone 2
avegfr3
Growing vegetable and nec in zone 3
avegfr4
Growing vegetable and nec in zone 4
avegfr5
Growing vegetable and nec in zone 5
aoils1
Growing oil seeds in zone 1
aoils2
Growing oil seeds in zone 2
aoils3
Growing oil seeds in zone 3
aoils4
Growing oil seeds in zone 4
aoils5
Growing oil seeds in zone 5
acash1
Growing cash crops nec in zone 1
acash2
Growing cash crops nec in zone 2
acash3
Growing cash crops nec in zone 3
acash4
Growing cash crops nec in zone 4
acash5
Growing cash crops nec in zone 5
aenset1
Growing enset in zone 1
aenset2
Growing enset in zone 2
aenset3
Growing enset in zone 3
aenset4
Growing enset in zone 4
aenset5
Growing enset in zone 5
acrop1
Growing crop nec in zone 1
acrop2
Growing crop nec in zone 2
acrop3
Growing crop nec in zone 3
acrop4
Growing crop nec in zone 4
acrop5
Growing crop nec in zone 5
acoff1
Growing coffee in zone 1
acoff2
Growing coffee in zone 2
acoff3
Growing coffee in zone 3
acoff4
Growing coffee in zone 4
alivst1
Livestock farming in zone 1
alivst2
Livestock farming in zone 2
alivst3
Livestock farming in zone 3
alivst4
Livestock farming in zone 4
alivst5
Livestock farming in zone 5
afisfor
Forestry and fishing
1.1.2 Industrial activities
Abbreviations
Descriptions
amining
Mining
aofood
Production, processing of food and related products
adairy
Manufacturing of dairy products
agmill
Manufacturing of grain mill products
agmillserv
Manufacturing of grain mill services
asug
Manufacture of sugar
abev
Manufacturing of beverage products
amtob
Manufacturing of tobacco products
atext
Manufacturing of textile products
aapar
Manufacturing of wearing apparels
aleath
Manufacturing of leather products
awood
Manufacturing of wood and products of wood
apaperp
Manufacture of paper and paper products
achem
Chemicals products manufacturing
aminprod
Mineral products manufacturing
abmetalp
Manufacturing metal products
amach
Machinery manufacturing
aelecq
Electronic equipments manufacturing
aveh
Motor vehicles manufacturing
aomanu
Furniture and related products manufacturing
1.1.3 Service activities
Abbreviations
Descriptions
aelect
Electricity
awater
Collection purification and distribution of water
acons
Service of construction
atrad
Trade
ahotel
Hotel
atrncom
Transport, communication and storage
afserv
Financial intermediation
arest
Real estate, business activities and renting
apadmin
Public administration
aeduc
Education
aheal
Health
aoserv
Business activities and related social services
1.1.4 Water fetching activities
Abbreviations
Descriptions
awfHH-Rural_EZ1Pagr
Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ1Pagr
awfHH-Rural_EZ1Pmix
Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ1Pmix
awfHH-Rural_EZ1Pnagr
Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ1Pnagr
awfHH-Rural_EZ2Pagr
Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ2Pagr
awfHH-Rural_EZ2Pmix
Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ2Pmix
awfHH-Rural_EZ2nagr
Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ2nagr
awfHH-Rural_EZ3Pagr
Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ3Pagr
awfHH-Rural_EZ3Pmix
Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ3Pmix
awfHH-Rural_EZ3Pnagr
Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ3Pnagr
awfHH-Rural_EZ4Pagr
Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ4PPagr
awfHH-Rural_EZ4Pmix
Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ4Pmix
awfHH-Rural_EZ4Pnagr
Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ4Pnagr
awfHH-Rural_EZ5Pagr
Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ5Pagr
awfHH-Rural_EZ5Pmix
Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ5Pmix
awfHH-Rural_EZ5Pnagr
Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ5Pnagr
awfHH-Rural_EZ1NPagr
Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ1NPagr
awfHH-Rural_EZ1NPmix
Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ1NPmix
awfHH-Rural_EZ1NPnagr
Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ1NPnagr
awfHH-Rural_EZ2NPagr
Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ2NPagr
awfHH-Rural_EZ2NPmix
Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ2NPmix
awfHH-Rural_EZ2NPnagr
Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ2NPnagr
awfHH-Rural_EZ3NPagr
Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ3NPagr
awfHH-Rural_EZ3NPmix
Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ3NPmix
awfHH-Rural_EZ3NPnagr
Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ3NPnagr
awfHH-Rural_EZ4NPagr
Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ4NPagr
awfHH-Rural_EZ4NPmix
Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ4NPmix
awfHH-Rural_EZ4NPnagr
Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ4NPnagr
awfHH-Rural_EZ5NPagr
Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ5NPagr
awfHH-Rural_EZ5NPmix
Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ5NPmix
awfHH-Rural_EZ5NPnagr
Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ5NPnagr
awfHH-SmallurbanP
Water fetching by HH-SmallurbanP
awfHH-BigurbanP
Water fetching by HH-BigurbanP
awfHH-SmallurbanNP
Water fetching by HH-SmallurbanNP
awfHH-BigurbanNP
Water fetching by HH-BigurbanNP
1.1.5 Firewood collection activities
Abbreviations
Descriptions
afwHH-Rural_EZ1Pagr
Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ1Pagr
afwHH-Rural_EZ1Pmix
Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ1Pmix
afwHH-Rural_EZ1Pnagr
Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ1Pnagr
afwHH-Rural_EZ2Pagr
Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ2Pagr
afwHH-Rural_EZ2Pmix
Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ2Pmix
afwHH-Rural_EZ2nagr
Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ2nagr
afwHH-Rural_EZ3Pagr
Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ3Pagr
afwHH-Rural_EZ3Pmix
Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ3Pmix
afwHH-Rural_EZ3Pnagr
Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ3Pnagr
afwHH-Rural_EZ4PPagr
Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ4PPagr
afwHH-Rural_EZ4Pmix
Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ4Pmix
afwHH-Rural_EZ4Pnagr
Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ4Pnagr
afwHH-Rural_EZ5Pagr
Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ5Pagr
afwHH-Rural_EZ5Pmix
Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ5Pmix
afwHH-Rural_EZ5Pnagr
Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ5Pnagr
afwHH-Rural_EZ1NPagr
Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ1NPagr
afwHH-Rural_EZ1NPmix
Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ1NPmix
afwHH-Rural_EZ1NPnagr
Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ1NPnagr
afwHH-Rural_EZ2NPagr
Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ2NPagr
afwHH-Rural_EZ2NPmix
Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ2NPmix
afwHH-Rural_EZ2NPnagr
Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ2NPnagr
afwHH-Rural_EZ3NPagr
Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ3NPagr
afwHH-Rural_EZ3NPmix
Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ3NPmix
afwHH-Rural_EZ3NPnagr
Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ3NPnagr
afwHH-Rural_EZ4NPagr
Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ4NPagr
afwHH-Rural_EZ4NPmix
Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ4NPmix
afwHH-Rural_EZ4NPnagr
Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ4NPnagr
afwHH-Rural_EZ5NPagr
Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ5NPagr
afwHH-Rural_EZ5NPmix
Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ5NPmix
afwHH-Rural_EZ5NPnagr
Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ5NPnagr
afwHH-SmallurbanP
Firewood collection by HH-SmallurbanP
afwHH-BigurbanP
Firewood collection by HH-BigurbanP
afwHH-SmallurbanNP
Firewood collection by HH-SmallurbanNP
afwHH-BigurbanNP
Firewood collection by HH-BigurbanNP
1.1.6 Leisure activities
Abbreviations
Descriptions
aLHH-Rural_EZ1Pagr
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ1Pagr
aLHH-Rural_EZ1Pmix
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ1Pmix
aLHH-Rural_EZ1Pnagr
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ1Pnagr
aLHH-Rural_EZ2Pagr
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ2Pagr
aLHH-Rural_EZ2Pmix
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ2Pmix
aLHH-Rural_EZ2nagr
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ2nagr
aLHH-Rural_EZ3Pagr
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ3Pagr
aLHH-Rural_EZ3Pmix
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ3Pmix
aLHH-Rural_EZ3Pnagr
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ3Pnagr
aLHH-Rural_EZ4Pagr
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ4Pagr
aLHH-Rural_EZ4Pmix
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ4Pmix
aLHH-Rural_EZ4Pnagr
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ4Pnagr
aLHH-Rural_EZ5Pagr
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ5Pagr
aLHH-Rural_EZ5Pmix
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ5Pmix
aLHH-Rural_EZ5Pnagr
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ5Pnagr
aLHH-Rural_EZ1NPagr
Leisure enjoyed by LHH-Rural_EZ1NPagr
aLHH-Rural_EZ1NPmix
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ1NPmix
aLHH-Rural_EZ1NPnagr
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ1NPnagr
aLHH-Rural_EZ2NPagr
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ2NPagr
aLHH-Rural_EZ2NPmix
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ2NPmix
aLHH-Rural_EZ2NPnagr
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ2NPnagr
aLHH-Rural_EZ3NPagr
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ3NPagr
aLHH-Rural_EZ3NPmix
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ3NPmix
aLHH-Rural_EZ3NPnagr
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ3NPnagr
aLHH-Rural_EZ4NPagr
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ4NPagr
aLHH-Rural_EZ4NPmix
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ4NPmix
aLHH-Rural_EZ4NPnagr
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ4NPnagr
aLHH-Rural_EZ5NPagr
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ5NPagr
aLHH-Rural_EZ5NPmix
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ5NPmix
aLHH-Rural_EZ5NPnagr
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ5NPnagr
aLHH-SmallurbanP
Leisure enjoyed by HH-SmallurbanP
aLHH-BigurbanP
Leisure enjoyed by HH-BigurbanP
aLHH-SmallurbanNP
Leisure enjoyed by HH-SmallurbanNP
aLHH-BigurbanNP
Leisure enjoyed by HH-BigurbanNP
1.2 Commodity accounts
1.2.1 Agricultural marketed commodities
Abbreviations
Descriptions
ctef
Teff
cbar
Barley
cwhea
Wheat
cmaiz
Maize
csorg
Sorghum
cpul
Pulse
cveg
Vegetable
coils
Oil seed
ccotts
Cotton seed
ccane
Sugar cane
cfruit
Fruit crops
ctea
Tea
cchat
Chat
ccoff
Coffee
censet
Enset
ccrop
Cereal grain and other crop
cfiber
Plant based fiber
ccatt
Cattle
cpoul
Poultry and other small livestock
cmilk
Raw milk
ccott
Raw cotton
caprod
Animal product
cfors
Forestry products
cflower
Flowers
cfish
Fish
1.2.2 Industrial marketed commodities
Abbreviations
Descriptions
ccoal
Coal
cngas
Gas
cmin
Minerals
cmeat
Meat
cvprod
Vegetable
cdairy
Dairy products
csug
Sugar
cgmill
Grain mill
cgmillserv
Grain mill services
cfood
Food
cbev
Beverages
ctob
Tobacco
cmtea
Tea manufacturing
cmtob
Tobacco manufacturing
clcott
Cotton
ctext
Textiles
capar
Wearing apparels
cleath
Leather
cwood
Wood
cpaper
Paper product
coilptrl
Petroleum coal
cfert
Fertilizers
cchem
Chemicals
cminprod
Mineral
cmetal
Metals
cmprod
Products of metal
cveh
Motor vehicles
celecq
Electronic equipment
cmach
Machinery
comanu
Products of manufacturing
1.2.3 Marketed services
Abbreviations
Descriptions
celect
Electricity
cwater
Water
ccons
Construction
ctrad
Trade
chotel
Hotel
ctrans
Transport service
ccomm
Communication
cfserv
Financial service
cbserv
Business service
cpadmin
Public administration
ceduc
Education
cheal
Health
coserv
Recreation and others
crest
Real estate and renting services
1.2.4 Home consumed agricultural commodities
Abbreviations
Descriptions
cmaizo
Maize
coilso
Oil seed
cvego
Vegetable
cwheao
Wheat
cbaro
Barley
cfruito
Fruit crops
csorgo
Sorghum
ctefo
Teff
cpulo
Pulses
ccaneo
Sugar cane
cchato
Chat
ccoffo
Coffee
censeto
Enset
ccropo
Grains
cpoulo
Poultry
cmilko
Raw milk
ccotto
Raw cotton
1.2.5 Home consumed processed (industrial) commodities
Abbreviations
Descriptions
caprodo
Animal products
cforso
Products of forestry
cfisho
Fish
cmeato
Meat
cdairyo
Dairy products
1.2.6 Home consumed service commodities
Abbreviations
Descriptions
cresto
Housing
1.2.7 Water fetching commodities
Abbreviations
Descriptions
cwfHH-Rural_EZ1Pagr
Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ1Pagr
cwfHH-Rural_EZ1Pmix
Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ1Pmix
cwfHH-Rural_EZ1Pnagr
Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ1Pnagr
cwfHH-Rural_EZ2Pagr
Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ2Pagr
cwfHH-Rural_EZ2Pmix
Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ2Pmix
cwfHH-Rural_EZ2nagr
Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ2nagr
cwfHH-Rural_EZ3Pagr
Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ3Pagr
cwfHH-Rural_EZ3Pmix
Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ3Pmix
cwfHH-Rural_EZ3Pnagr
Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ3Pnagr
cwfHH-Rural_EZ4Pagr
Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ4Pagr
cwfHH-Rural_EZ4Pmix
Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ4Pmix
cwfHH-Rural_EZ4Pnagr
Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ4Pnagr
cwfHH-Rural_EZ5Pagr
Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ5Pagr
cwfHH-Rural_EZ5Pmix
Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ5Pmix
cwfHH-Rural_EZ5Pnagr
Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ5Pnagr
cwfHH-Rural_EZ1NPagr
Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ1NPagr
cwfHH-Rural_EZ1NPmix
Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ1NPmix
cwfHH-Rural_EZ1NPnagr
Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ1NPnagr
cwfHH-Rural_EZ2NPagr
Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ2NPagr
cwfHH-Rural_EZ2NPmix
Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ2NPmix
cwfHH-Rural_EZ2NPnagr
Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ2NPnagr
cwfHH-Rural_EZ3NPagr
Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ3NPagr
cwfHH-Rural_EZ3NPmix
Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ3NPmix
cwfHH-Rural_EZ3NPnagr
Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ3NPnagr
cwfHH-Rural_EZ4NPagr
Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ4NPagr
cwfHH-Rural_EZ4NPmix
Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ4NPmix
cwfHH-Rural_EZ4NPnagr
Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ4NPnagr
cwfHH-Rural_EZ5NPagr
Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ5NPagr
cwfHH-Rural_EZ5NPmix
Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ5NPmix
cwfHH-Rural_EZ5NPnagr
Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ5NPnagr
cwfHH-SmallurbanP
Water consumed by HH-SmallurbanP
cwfHH-BigurbanP
Water consumed by HH-BigurbanP
cwfHH-SmallurbanNP
Water consumed by HH-SmallurbanNP
cwfHH-BigurbanNP
Water consumed by HH-BigurbanNP
1.2.8: Firewood collection commodities
Abbreviations
Descriptions
cfwHH-Rural_EZ1Pagr
Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ1Pagr
cfwHH-Rural_EZ1Pmix
Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ1Pmix
cfwHH-Rural_EZ1Pnagr
Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ1Pnagr
cfwHH-Rural_EZ2Pagr
Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ2Pagr
cfwHH-Rural_EZ2Pmix
Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ2Pmix
cfwHH-Rural_EZ2nagr
Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ2nagr
cfwHH-Rural_EZ3Pagr
Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ3Pagr
cfwHH-Rural_EZ3Pmix
Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ3Pmix
cfwHH-Rural_EZ3Pnagr
Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ3Pnagr
cfwHH-Rural_EZ4Pagr
Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ4Pagr
cfwHH-Rural_EZ4Pmix
Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ4Pmix
cfwHH-Rural_EZ4Pnagr
Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ4Pnagr
cfwHH-Rural_EZ5Pagr
Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ5Pagr
cfwHH-Rural_EZ5Pmix
Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ5Pmix
cfwHH-Rural_EZ5Pnagr
Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ5Pnagr
cfwHH-Rural_EZ1NPagr
Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ1NPagr
cfwHH-Rural_EZ1NPmix
Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ1NPmix
cfwHH-Rural_EZ1NPnagr
Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ1NPnagr
cfwHH-Rural_EZ2NPagr
Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ2NPagr
cfwHH-Rural_EZ2NPmix
Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ2NPmix
cfwHH-Rural_EZ2NPnagr
Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ2NPnagr
cfwHH-Rural_EZ3NPagr
Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ3NPagr
cfwHH-Rural_EZ3NPmix
Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ3NPmix
cfwHH-Rural_EZ3NPnagr
Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ3NPnagr
cfwHH-Rural_EZ4NPagr
Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ4NPagr
cfwHH-Rural_EZ4NPmix
Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ4NPmix
cfwHH-Rural_EZ4NPnagr
Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ4NPnagr
cfwHH-Rural_EZ5NPagr
Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ5NPagr
cfwHH-Rural_EZ5NPmix
Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ5NPmix
cfwHH-RuralE_Z5NPnagr
Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ5NPnagr
cfwHH-SmallurbanP
Firewood consumed by HH-SmallurbanP
cfwHH-BigurbanP
Firewood consumed by HH-BigurbanP
cfwHH-SmallurbanNP
Firewood consumed by HH-SmallurbanNP
cfwHH-BigurbanNP
Firewood consumed by HH-BigurbanNP
1.2.9 Leisure commodities
Abbreviations
Descriptions
cLHH-Rural_EZ1Pagr
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ1Pagr
cLHH-Rural_EZ1Pmix
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ1Pmix
cLHH-Rural_EZ1Pnagr
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ1Pnagr
cLHH-Rural_EZ2Pagr
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ2Pagr
cLHH-Rural_EZ2Pmix
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ2Pmix
cLHH-Rural_EZ2nagr
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ2nagr
cLHH-Rural_EZ3Pagr
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ3Pagr
cLHH-Rural_EZ3Pmix
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ3Pmix
cLHH-Rural_EZ3Pnagr
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ3Pnagr
cLHH-Rural_EZ4Pagr
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ4Pagr
cLHH-Rural_EZ4Pmix
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ4Pmix
cLHH-Rural_EZ4Pnagr
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ4Pnagr
cLHH-Rural_EZ5Pagr
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ5Pagr
cLHH-Rural_EZ5Pmix
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ5Pmix
cLHH-Rural_EZ5Pnagr
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ5Pnagr
cLHH-Rural_EZ1NPagr
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ1NPagr
cLHH-Rural_EZ1NPmix
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ1NPmix
cLHH-Rural_EZ1NPnagr
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ1NPnagr
cLHH-Rural_EZ2NPagr
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ2NPagr
cLHH-Rural_EZ2NPmix
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ2NPmix
cLHH-Rural_EZ2NPnagr
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ2NPnagr
cLHH-Rural_EZ3NPagr
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ3NPagr
cLHH-Rural_EZ3NPmix
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ3NPmix
cLHH-Rural_EZ3NPnagr
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ3NPnagr
cLHH-Rural_EZ4NPagr
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ4NPagr
cLHH-Rural_EZ4NPmix
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ4NPmix
cLHH-Rural_EZ4NPnagr
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ4NPnagr
cLHH-Rural_EZ5NPagr
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ5NPagr
cLHH-Rural_EZ5NPmix
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ5NPmix
cLHH-Rural_EZ5NPnagr
Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ5NPnagr
cLHH-SmallurbanP
Leisure enjoyed by HH-SmallurbanP
cLHH-BigurbanP
Leisure enjoyed by HH-BigurbanP
cLHH-SmallurbanNP
Leisure enjoyed by HH-SmallurbanNP
cLHH-BigurbanNP
Leisure enjoyed by HH-BigurbanNP
1.3 Household accounts
Abbreviations
Descriptions
HH-Rural_EZ1Pagr
Household rural zone 1 poor agricultural
HH-Rural_EZ1Pmix
Household rural zone 1 poor mixed
HH-Rural_EZ1Pnagr
Household rural zone 1 poor non-agricultural
HH-Rural_EZ2Pagr
Household rural zone 2 poor agricultural
HH-Rural_EZ2Pmix
Household rural zone 2 poor mixed
HH-Rural_EZ2nagr
Household rural zone 2 poor non-agricultural
HH-Rural_EZ3Pagr
Household rural zone 3 poor agricultural
HH-Rural_EZ3Pmix
Household rural zone 3 poor mixed
HH-Rural_EZ3Pnagr
Household rural zone 3 poor non-agricultural
HH-Rural_EZ4Pagr
Household rural zone 4 poor agricultural
HH-Rural_EZ4Pmix
Household rural zone 4 poor mixed
HH-Rural_EZ4Pnagr
Household rural zone 4 poor non-agricultural
HH-Rural_EZ5Pagr
Household rural zone 5 poor agricultural
HH-Rural_EZ5Pmix
Household rural zone 5 poor mixed
HH-Rural_EZ5Pnagr
Household rural zone 5 poor non-agricultural
HH-Rural_EZ1NPagr
Household rural zone 1 non-poor agricultural
HH-Rural_EZ1NPmix
Household rural zone 1 non-poor mixed
HH-Rural_EZ1NPnagr
Household rural zone 1 non-poor non-agricultural
HH-Rural_EZ2NPagr
Household rural zone 2 non-poor agricultural
HH-Rural_EZ2NPmix
Household rural zone 2 non-poor mixed
HH-Rural_EZ2NPnagr
Household rural zone 2 non-poor non-agricultural
HH-Rural_EZ3NPagr
Household rural zone 3 non-poor agricultural
HH-Rural_EZ3NPmix
Household rural zone 3 non-poor mixed
HH-Rural_EZ3NPnagr
Household rural zone 3 non-poor non-agricultural
HH-Rural_EZ4NPagr
Household rural zone 4 non-poor agricultural
HH-Rural_EZ4NPmix
Household rural zone 4 non-poor mixed
HH-Rural_EZ4NPnagr
Household rural zone 4 non-poor non-agricultural
HH-Rural_EZ5NPagr
Household rural zone 5 non-poor agricultural
HH-Rural_EZ5NPmix
Household rural zone 5 non-poor mixed
HH-Rural_EZ5NPnagr
Household rural zone 5 non-poor non-agricultural
HH-SmallurbanP
Household small urban poor
HH-BigurbanP
Household big urban poor
HH-SmallurbanNP
Household small urban non-poor
HH-BigurbanNP
Household big urban non-poor
1.4 Factor accounts
1.4.1 Labor accounts
Abbreviations
Descriptions
Agrm
Agricultural labor male
Agrf
Agricultural labor female
Admm
Administrative labor male
Admf
Administrative labor female
Profm
Professional labor male
Proff
Professional labor female
Unskm
Unskilled labor male
Unskf
Unskilled labor female
Skm
Skilled labor male
Skf
Skilled labor female
1.4.2 Non-labor factors
Abbreviations
Descriptions
Capital_Land_RuralEZ1P
Capital land for rural poor in zone 1
Capital_Land_RuralEZ1NP
Capital land for rural non-poor in zone 1
Capital_Land_RuralEZ2P
Capital land for rural poor in zone 2
Capital_Land_RuralEZ2NP
Capital land for rural non-poor in zone 2
Capital_Land_RuralEZ3P
Capital land for rural poor in zone 3
Capital_Land_RuralEZ3NP
Capital land for rural non-poor in zone 3
Capital_Land_RuralEZ4P
Capital land for rural poor in zone 4
Capital_Land_RuralEZ4NP
Capital land for rural non-poor in zone 4
Capital_Land_RuralEZ5P
Capital land for rural poor in zone 5
Capital_Land_RuralEZ5NP
Capital land for rural non-poor in zone 5
Capital_Livst_RuralEZ1P
Capital livestock for rural poor in zone 1
Capital_Livst_RuralEZ1NP
Capital livestock for rural non-poor in zone 1
Capital_Livst_RuralEZ2P
Capital livestock for rural poor in zone 2
Capital_Livst_RuralEZ2NP
Capital livestock for rural non-poor in zone 2
Capital_Livst_RuralEZ3P
Capital livestock for rural poor in zone 3
Capital_Livst_RuralEZ3NP
Capital livestock for rural non-poor in zone 3
Capital_Livst_RuralEZ4P
Capital livestock for rural poor in zone 4
Capital_Livst_RuralEZ4NP
Capital livestock for rural non-poor in zone 4
Capital_Livst_RuralEZ5P
Capital livestock for rural poor in zone 5
Capital_Livst_RuralEZ5NP
Capital livestock for rural non-poor in zone 5
Non_Agg_capital
Non-agricultural capital
1.5 Other accounts
Abbreviations
Descriptions
ENT
Enterprises
GOVT
Government
TotalMargin
Transport margins
DSTOC
Stock changes
KAP
Savings
ROW
Rest of the world
1.6 Tax accounts
Abbreviations
Descriptions
LandTx
Land use tax
CapGainTx
Capital gains tax
IntIncTax
Interest income tax
RentIncTx
Rental income tax
DivTx
Dividend tax
ProfitTx
Profit tax
AgIncTx
Income tax (agricultural)
HHIncTx
Income tax (personal)
OEntTx
Other direct taxes
Impsur
Surtax from import
ImpVAT
Value added tax from import
ImpEcsTx
Excise tax from import
ImpWTx
Import withholding tax
ImpDuty
Import tax
ServTx
Service tax
LocEcsTx
Domestic excise tax
LocalVAT
Domestic value added tax
Appendix 2: Sensitivity of model results to changes in the income elasticity of leisure
2.1 Sensitivity of labor demand and production (percentage)
Labor demand by activities
Eyleisure* = 2
Eyleisure= 3
Eyleisure= 4
Agriculture
1.61
1.16
0.82
Industry
0.88
1.07
1.28
Service
0.54
0.81
1.10
Water fetching
− 21.65
− 23.56
− 24.91
Firewood collection
− 22.35
− 24.13
− 25.39
Leisure
4.62
5.63
6.34
Production by activities
Eyleisure = 2
Eyleisure = 3
Eyleisure = 4
Agriculture
1.21
0.89
0.65
Industry
0.59
0.61
0.63
Service
0.42
0.48
0.55
Water fetching
17.53
14.66
12.64
Firewood collection
16.48
13.81
11.91
Leisure
4.62
5.63
6.34
2.2 Sensitivity of welfare (EV/base income) to changes in the income elasticity of leisure
Households
Eyleisure = 2
Eyleisure = 3
Eyleisure = 4
HH-Rural_EZ1Pagr
6.88
6.82
6.80
HH-Rural_EZ1Pmix
6.88
6.82
6.80
HH-Rural_EZ1Pnagr
6.88
6.82
6.80
HH-Rural_EZ2Pagr
4.88
4.89
4.91
HH-Rural_EZ2Pmix
4.88
4.89
4.91
HH-Rural_EZ2nagr
4.88
4.89
4.91
HH-Rural_EZ3Pagr
5.35
5.34
5.34
HH-Rural_EZ3Pmix
5.35
5.34
5.34
HH-Rural_EZ3Pnagr
5.35
5.34
5.34
HH-Rural_EZ4Pagr
4.84
4.85
4.86
HH-Rural_EZ4Pmix
4.98
4.96
4.95
HH-Rural_EZ4Pnagr
4.98
4.96
4.95
HH-Rural_EZ5Pagr
6.94
6.76
6.64
HH-Rural_EZ5Pmix
6.94
6.76
6.64
HH-Rural_EZ5Pnagr
6.94
6.76
6.64
HH-Rural_EZ1NPagr
5.16
5.12
5.10
HH-Rural_EZ1NPmix
5.16
5.12
5.10
HH-Rural_EZ1NPnagr
5.16
5.12
5.10
HH-Rural_EZ2NPagr
3.19
3.16
3.13
HH-Rural_EZ2NPmix
3.19
3.16
3.13
HH-Rural_EZ2NPnagr
3.19
3.16
3.13
HH-Rural_EZ3NPagr
3.86
3.83
3.82
HH-Rural_EZ3NPmix
3.86
3.83
3.82
HH-Rural_EZ3NPnagr
3.76
3.75
3.74
HH-Rural_EZ4NPagr
3.46
3.41
3.37
HH-Rural_EZ4NPmix
3.46
3.41
3.37
HH-Rural_EZ4NPnagr
3.46
3.41
3.37
HH-Rural_EZ5NPagr
5.69
5.52
5.40
HH-Rural_EZ5NPmix
5.69
5.52
5.40
HH-Rural_EZ5NPnagr
5.69
5.52
5.40
HH-SmallurbanP
1.50
1.31
1.12
HH-BigurbanP
1.91
1.85
1.80
HH-SmallurbanNP
− 3.75
− 4.03
− 4.28
HH-BigurbanNP
− 1.54
− 1.72
− 1.89
2.3 Sensitivity of macroeconomic effects (percentage) to changes in the income elasticity of leisure
Real macroeconomic indicators
Eyleisure = 2
Eyleisure = 3
Eyleisure = 4
Absorption
2.76
2.64
2.67
Import
1.50
1.43
1.38
GDP from expenditure
2.62
2.56
2.52
Total domestic production
2.00
1.96
1.93
Rights and permissions
Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article's Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article's Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/.
Mosa, A., Grethe, H. & Siddig, K. Economy-wide effects of reducing the time spent for water fetching and firewood collection in Ethiopia.
Environ Syst Res9, 20 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1186/s40068-020-00189-y